Tumgik
#substitute poor for any other marginalized group and see how it sounds
whitmore · 5 months
Text
classism is never the move, it’s inevitably going to be received in bad taste, as it should be, you cannot openly hate poor people and think everybody should be cool with that, you can’t enable that kind of behaviour and think everybody should be cool with that
26 notes · View notes
Link
Carbon taxes are in the news these days. In recent months, not one but two conservative national carbon tax proposals have emerged, disrupting the usual partisan dynamic on climate policy.
First there was the proposal from the Climate Leadership Council, a group of (mostly older, retired) Republicans and centrists, which was released last year but recently gained the backing of a new big-money conservative PAC. And next week, Rep. Carlos Curbelo (R-FL), co-chair of the House Climate Solutions Caucus, plans to release a carbon-tax proposal of his own.
Neither proposal has a snowflake’s chance in hell of passage any time soon. And on Thursday, the House passed a resolution trying to squash even the possibility of a carbon tax. But the existence of these proposals does indicate a heightened level of awareness of and interest in carbon taxes. So now seems like a good opportunity to review some of the basics.
Luckily, the Center on Global Energy Policy (CGEP) at Columbia University (in conjunction with several other research organizations) has just issued a series of four research papers covering those basics. The research didn’t turn up anything particularly shocking; it mostly confirmed what policy wonks have long understood about the dynamics of carbon taxes.
But those dynamics aren’t necessarily well understood by the public. With the (slim but growing!) chance that a federal carbon tax could be the subject of serious national debate, it’s a good time for everyone to get up to speed.
Rep. Carlos Curbelo (R-FL). Alex Wong/Getty Images
A carbon tax is just what it sounds like — a per-ton tax on the carbon dioxide emissions embedded in fuels or other products. (Other greenhouse gases, like methane, are translated into their carbon dioxide equivalent, or CO2e, for easier comparison.)
Here are the top five questions advocates, policymakers, and informed citizens should be asking about a carbon tax:
Can it reduce greenhouse gas emissions?
What economic sectors will it hit hardest?
What overall effect will it have on the US economy?
Will it be fair and equitable?
Will it be enough to address climate change?
Let’s walk through what the research shows, one answer at a time.
The CGEP research pivots around a few shared scenarios. Researchers modeled three different carbon taxes — starting at a per-ton rate of $14 (rising 3 percent a year), $50 (rising 2 percent a year), and $73 (rising 1.5 percent a year) respectively — with a range of fairly conservative assumptions about energy prices and technology development. The $50 tax served as the central case.
In all cases, the tax would be charged “upstream,” where carbon enters the economy, at the wellhead, mine shaft, or import terminal. The tax would ultimately cover more than 80 percent of the economy’s total greenhouse gas emissions.
The research consultancy Rhodium Group, which analyzed the energy and emission effects of a tax for CGEP, found that, sure enough, it will reduce greenhouse gas emissions.
Under the $50/ton scenario, emissions fall 39 to 46 percent below 2005 levels by 2025, putting the US well ahead of its pledged Paris goal of 26 to 28 percent by 2025. (Current policy, as Rhodium’s previous research has shown, is not enough to hit that goal.)
RHG
However, none of the taxes considered are likely to achieve the long-term US emission goal of 80 percent below 2005 levels by 2050 (a target we now realize is woefully insufficient) “absent complementary GHG policies, significant improvements in technologies that can act as direct substitutes for fossil fuels, and/or significantly faster electrification of the transportation, buildings, and industrial sectors than we considered in this analysis.”
As the low-hanging fruit is consumed, emission reductions start getting more expensive. To get to 80 percent (or more appropriately, 100 percent) reductions, carbon prices would likely need to exceed $100/ton by mid-century.
A carbon tax can reduce emissions quickly, but in the early years, reductions come overwhelmingly from a single industry: electricity.
The most striking result of the Rhodium research is that more than 80 percent of the emission reductions achieved by a carbon tax through 2030 would come from the electricity sector. More specifically, they would come from the accelerated decline of coal.
RHG
The same is not true for other sectors of the economy.
“Due to nonprice barriers, stock turnover constraints, higher capital cost to operating cost ratios, and a smaller set of abatement opportunities,” Rhodium writes, “end-use sector emissions see modest declines in emissions.”
In particular, transportation appears stubbornly resistant to carbon prices. Through 2030, a $50 carbon tax would reduce emissions from the transportation sector all of … 2 percent.
RHG
Why the stark difference?
First, there aren’t easily available short-term substitutes in transportation like there are in electricity. In the electricity sector, operators can easily ramp down coal plants and ramp up natural gas plants. But in transportation, without commercially available liquid-fuel alternatives, the only way to reduce emissions quickly is to drive less, and driving behavior has proven resistant to price pressure.
Second, carbon taxes put more pressure on operating costs than on capital costs. The electricity sector is weighted toward operating costs (the power plants are mostly already built), while the transportation sector is weighted toward capital costs, i.e., the cost of buying the vehicle. A carbon tax affects the cost of running a power plant much more than it affects the cost of buying a car.
The results are not quite as stark for the industrial and building sectors, but they are pretty close. Those sectors are somewhat more amenable to price-driven carbon reductions than transportation, but not nearly as amenable as electricity (though the researchers note that uncertainty is higher in those sectors, since reporting and data are not as consistent).
Republicans’ favorite attack on a carbon tax (or any clean air, water, or energy policy) is that it will raise costs and slow economic growth — that it will be, in the words of the anti-carbon-tax resolution the House just passed, “detrimental to the United States economy.” (By the way, 39 of the 43 Republicans in Curbelo’s House Climate Solutions Caucus voted for that resolution.)
House Majority Whip Steve Scalise, who sponsored the anti-carbon-tax resolution. Aaron P. Bernstein/Getty Images
Is it true?
The Baker Institute for Public Policy at Rice University did the research on a carbon tax’s macroeconomic effects. In a nutshell, the macroeconomic effect of a carbon tax varies depending on what the government does with the revenue.
The key point, though, is that in every scenario, the macroeconomic effect is small — well under 1 percent of GDP in either direction. The fact is, even a relatively large carbon tax won’t dramatically affect a $20 trillion economy. In practice, the macroeconomic effects of any carbon tax are likely to be lost amid larger demographic and economic trends.
The research examined three uses of the revenue through 2030:
Using it to reduce payroll taxes would result in a net increase in GDP (of around 0.5 percent), along with boosts in “total investment, consumption, and labor supply,” because payroll taxes are distortionary and reducing them leads to more optimal economic performance;
Using it for per-capita dividends results in a modest decrease in both GDP (0.4 percent) and consumption (0.6 percent), because “the carbon tax-induced increases in consumer prices that lead to reductions in real wages are not offset by the recycling of carbon tax revenues”;
Using it to reduce the national debt boosts GDP 0.3 percent but reduces consumption by 0.4 percent.
As I said, all of these effects are relatively small, which suggests to me that macroeconomic effect should not be the deciding factor in how to design a carbon tax. It may be that a small marginal decline in the rate of GDP growth is a small price to pay for more justice, or emission reductions, or political durability.
One other note here: It is irksome that the only scenarios modeled are revenue-neutral. All the revenue is returned, none left for government spending.
As I’ve written before, that is an essentially conservative restriction on carbon-tax design. There’s no reason climate hawks should go along with it. The US is nowhere near overtaxed and we have lots of big spending needs if we’re going to address climate change (like, say, a Green New Deal).
So why not rebate (or reduce payroll taxes) enough to protect low- and middle-income Americans and then use the rest for clean energy infrastructure and transition assistance for vulnerable communities?
A good target for some government spending in Puerto Rico. Ricardo Arduengo/AFP via Getty Images
I asked Noah Kaufman, who directs the carbon tax research effort at Columbia’s School of International and Public Affairs, about this. He said it was less about researchers’ preferences than “modeling limitations.”
“Economic models in this space are typically not designed to do revenue positive scenarios,” he told me, “and in my experience, modelers are uncomfortable with the idea of projecting the economic impacts of additional government spending.” He hopes, as do I, that modelers get a little more adventurous in this respect. Of all the reasons to make a carbon tax revenue-neutral, “difficulty modeling anything else” is among the worst.
A carbon tax is, in and of itself, somewhat regressive. It hits the poor harder than the rich because the poor spend a larger percentage of their income on energy services. However, it also generates a lot of revenue — between $740 billion (in the $14/ton scenario) and $3 trillion (in the $73/ton scenario) over 10 years — which can be used to offset the regressivity.
So the distributional effects of the tax depend on how the revenue is used. We can design a progressive carbon tax if we want one.
The Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center did the research on the “Distributional Implications of a Carbon Tax.” The researchers modeled four possible uses of the revenue: “reducing the federal deficit, reducing payroll taxes, reducing the corporate income tax, and providing per capita household rebates.”
Here’s how they summarize the results:
When revenue is used to reduce the deficit, a carbon tax is moderately regressive—that is, it increases taxes by a larger percentage of income for lower-income households than for higher-income households. Using revenue to reduce the corporate income tax (beyond the corporate tax cut in the recent Tax Cuts and Jobs Act) would result in higher taxes for low-income families and disproportionate benefits for higher-income taxpayers. Using revenue to provide lump-sum rebates would more than offset the carbon tax burden for low- and middle-income taxpayers but leave high-income families with a net tax increase. Using carbon tax revenues to reduce employee payroll taxes would result in a net benefit for upper middle-income taxpayers, while increasing tax burdens modestly for low-income and the highest-income households.
Here’s a chart that sums it all up:
TPC
So if you’re aiming for the most net-progressive tax, you use the revenue for rebates — helps the low-income, raises taxes on the high-income. If you’re aiming to appeal to the middle class, you use the revenue for payroll tax reductions — helps the middle, increases taxes on either end.
If you’re looking to be a soulless plutocrat, you use the revenue to (even further) reduce corporate taxes, thus helping your wealthy buddies and screwing everyone else. And if you’re a daft “centrist” gripped by baseless fears about the deficit, you use the revenue to pay down the debt and pat yourself on the back even as everyone is worse off. Ahem.
It’s pretty clear that anyone concerned about the welfare of low- and middle-income Americans is obligated to support a carbon tax design that sends at least some of the revenue back to them — at least enough so that they suffer no net harm to their pre-tax income.
But, again, I’m irritated by the background assumption that all the revenue must be automatically returned, that the tax must be revenue-neutral. I’d like some modeling that reveals exactly how much of the revenue must be returned to hold low- and middle-income Americans whole. I suspect there would be quite a bit left over to spend on clean energy.
Here we depart from the Columbia research and I add one answer of my own.
The economic theory behind carbon prices is that, if carbon is priced correctly — i.e., at the true “social cost of carbon” — then the economy will respond with the optimal level of carbon reduction.
There are all kinds of difficulties with this theory, not least determining the social cost of carbon, which is as much art and ethics as it is science.
But the main problem is less theoretical than practical: Political resistance has kept carbon prices well below any reasonable social cost of carbon pretty much everywhere carbon prices have been implemented. Nowhere in the US, certainly not in the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative or the Western Climate Initiative, or even the carbon tax in BC, has carbon prices close to $50/ton, which is the central case in the Columbia research. (Prices in the EU’s carbon trading system are just over $19/ton.)
And some researchers believe that the true social cost of carbon may be much higher than today’s estimates, as high as $250/ton.
Theoretically, carbon taxes can achieve any level of emission reduction. Just crank the price up — change the model inputs until you get the outputs you need. But politically, carbon prices have been constrained far below optimal levels. Nowhere, in practice, are they doing enough on their own.
To me, all of the above suggests a simple conclusion: Carbon taxes are good policy, an important part of the portfolio, but unlikely ever to be sufficient on their own. It’s worth getting a price on carbon anywhere it can be gotten, but climate hawks should not believe, and definitely shouldn’t be saying in public, that a carbon price is enough, that it’s worth trading anything and everything for, that when we implement it, we are done.
For one thing, it’s unlikely to be high enough. For another, it strikes me as unwise to leave other sectors unreformed for a decade or two while we clean up electricity. If that happens, we could reach 2030 or 2040, run out of coal to retire, and find ourselves needing very rapid, very large reductions from those other sectors, for which we will be ill-prepared.
I asked Kaufman, the director of Columbia’s School of International and Public Affairs, about this as well. He noted that “it’s a feature rather than a bug of a carbon tax policy that its near-term effects are concentrated in one industry.” That should serve to reduce political opposition from oil and gas.
But he also added, “if I were developing an optimal climate policy portfolio, I’d absolutely include a host of other policies, like funding clean transportation infrastructure, efficiency standards, and a boatload of support for innovation.”
John Larsen, director of the Rhodium research, told me that the sectoral analysis of carbon tax effects can show policymakers “where to focus additional policy action.”
“A very reasonable case can be made from our results,” he said, “that more action across the economy is required if the US is going to do its fair share in tackling climate change.”
Carbon pricing, whatever form it comes in, will almost certainly need to be supplemented with technology research, development, and demonstration policies; pollution regulations; and spending on infrastructure, adaptation, and transition assistance. A carbon price supports, funds, and accelerates the effects of those other policies (which is great!), but it is not a substitute.
The proper target for advocacy is action sufficient to reduce emissions to net-zero carbon as fast as practicably possible. What limits that effort is not ultimately the choice of policy instruments, but the constraints of political attention, organization, funding, and intensity. Loosen those constraints and everything, including a carbon tax, gets easier.
Original Source -> The 5 most important questions about carbon taxes, answered
via The Conservative Brief
0 notes
rickzimmer · 7 years
Text
Part-Time Law School
Here is a great post from one of our junior associates about different ways to finish law school.
“After successfully completing an evening law school program while working full time, there are a few words of wisdom and advice to share. First, although it is most like referred to as a part-time program, but would be better described as the “Evening Division” program. A full course caseload in law school is approximately 12 credits or 4 classes per semester.
In order to graduate in 4-5 years, a requirement of most accredited law schools, you will carry 9 -11 credits per semester (or more) every semester in law school (Summer semester you will probably only have to take 4-7 credits). This is not an easy task. You will have to be extremely organized and disciplined both at work and in your studies. There will not be a minute to waste. Your life will be highly scheduled and there will be little room for error, especially during the first year – which is the hardest of all.
The practice of law is all about preparation, and law school professors are keen to force you to learn the lessons of preparation. In spite of the fact that most law school professors are poor educators, and should not be teaching anyone, you will successfully learn the material if you apply yourself. Train yourself to prepare for every class by following the professor’s syllabus to the letter, and be ready to answer when called on. When the professor calls, be ready to answer. Nothing sends a law school professor into madness faster than law school students ill-prepared for class. The professor will take his anger out on everyone, and that is not fun. Please be prepared…it will be less painful for you and your classmates!
Because law school professors are not necessarily good teachers, you must be resourceful and find other ways to teach yourself the material beyond the case law and lectures—which, for the most part, can be difficult to understand. Finding a detailed course outline on the internet, or purchasing commercial outlines is a very good idea. However, do not think you will be able to rely on these resources alone. If you do, it will be a grave mistake and your GPA will show it. You must use other resources only to further your own understanding, not as a substitute for your own work. For every course, you should create your own detailed outline based on the professor’s syllabus. This way, you will learn what the professor wants you to know for the exam. Supplement your outline as necessary with explanations or highlights from other outlines.
Study groups were not useful only because of the time and effort spent preparing for each class, and also my work schedule. Others of my classmates could not survive without a study group. I think this was because they were distracted (Facebook or internet shopping) during class – or being too tired. Luckily, I was able to pay full attention throughout class, and did not allow myself to be distracted, so there was no need for me to take time traveling to participate in a study group, or trying to rearrange my schedule to attend a group where other students were trying to figure out the material. Pay attention during class. My study time was much better spent reading or working on my own outline, rather than with a group of people who didn’t know the material. The one thing that was marginally helpful in the later years was to collaborate with a small group on preparing an outline. I did not do this often, but carrying a heavy caseload sometimes necessitated it, and I developed trustworthy relationships my classmates, so it worked out. Even so, I went over the contributions of others very carefully. I rarely relied on others, and I would definitely pass that advice along.
Buy used books! Law school text books are outrageously priced — $250 for a textbook. During my first years, I thought I needed the brand new, clean books. During my last years, I sometimes found used books on Amazon or Barnes and Noble for less than $25. The same goes for used study aids. You don’t have to spend a ton. Check out the reviews of the seller. I never had an issue with buying used. Also, whether you drive or use public transportation, do yourself a HUGE favor and purchase audio downloads of law school courses . Bar prep audio courses are helpful for law school classes, too. I supplemented my learning this way and got A’s every time.
Definitely ask the professor for old exams to prepare. Use the law library to get any old exams you can, and practice. It occasionally happened that a professor would use a repeat question from an old test. What a bonus for preparing. Also, use commercial question & answer (Q&A) aids for studying. It will help prepare you for the multiple choice questions on your exams, and even if your exam is only essay questions, the Q&A has detailed answers so you will learn from your mistakes and be able to write better essays.
Most law school courses have only one exam during the semester, so your grade boils down to one performance and one performance only! The exams are three or four hour long marathons of non-stop writing. If you are working full-time, use your vacation time wisely, and take days off during final exams to study, rest and prepare. Being nice to your supervisor at work, and staying on top of work responsibilities will definitely pay off during the exam period.
Other random advice includes cooking meals for the week on Sundays, so that you can take something to school in the evenings to eat. You do not want to live on fast food while you are taxing your body and your brain. You will get sick if you don’t take care of yourself. Also, make a bed-time routine and stick to it. Every night I came home around 9:15. I usually grabbed a snack, watched a TV show to unwind, and then was in bed by 11:00. Alarm went off at 6 or 6:30. Sometimes, in the morning, I would catch up on reading for the evening class or do homework in the morning before leaving for work. Sticking to a routine is essential. I tried exercising off and on – mostly off. It definitely helped, but I confess that I wasn’t regular with it. You will do better and find time to exercise! Between semesters, make sure to do something fun—take a vacation. Kick back and rest your mind. Spend as much time as you can with friends and family whom you have completely ignored while running from work to school and back to work. Hopefully, they will understand your plight and you have everyone’s support.
As you can see, succeeding in law school requires discipline and preparation. This is the way it will be when you are an attorney. So, look at law school not only as learning to think like a lawyer, but also view it as practical preparation for being a lawyer in the real world. If all of this sounds horrendous to you, please run, do not walk away from your law school application…and save your time and money for something you really want.”
This post shows how even the busiest person can successfully attend and complete law school. This is the kind of talent and dedication we are looking for at the Rick Zimmer Law Firm.
The post Part-Time Law School appeared first on The Rick Zimmer Law Firm.
from The Rick Zimmer Law Firm http://www.rickzimmer.com/part-time-law-school/
0 notes